Minneapolis
like many American cities is facing a housing affordability crisis. Rents
are going up rapidly, placing
middle class and low income households into units beyond what they can afford,
if in fact they can even find suitable unit at all. Among solutions being considered in Minneapolis and elsewhere
is rent control or stabilization. Is
that a viable solution?
The case for rent control is simple: Freeze rents or limit increases to reasonable costs plus indexed inflation. The hope is that this will squeeze unfair
profiteering out of the housing market and
eventually make units more affordable.
Evidence does suggest that rent control
helps existing tenants, including
encouraging them to remain in
their current units for years. This may
stabilize neighborhoods in healthy ways,
perhaps increasing a sense of community and the building of social
capital. Rent control done right, will
possibly stem the migration of middle class out of a city, also an important
goal.
But the textbook economist’s
answer to whether rent control works is no. For an economist, housing is like any other
commodity that responds to market forces of supply and demand. The only way to decrease the cost of housing
is to increase the supply. However, this solution does not always work. Developers, left to their own devices and
market incentives, will build units that yield the highest profit margin, and that is not necessarily middle
class or low income housing. Housing
markets are segregated by income or class, and simply building more units will
not translate into serving the overall housing market or populations. The best way to provide affordable middle
class or low income units is to build them to serve that market.
But economists will argue that rent
control does not work because of the market externalities it produces. One, place caps on the rent that landlords
can charge, and they will delay maintenance.
Two, rent control creates disincentives to build new units since the
profits will not be there. Three, owners
will convert existing rental units to condos or coops in avoid rent control,
thereby exacerbating the rental shortage.
Four, developers will move housing construction outside of the rent
control jurisdiction, again aggravating shortages. Five, rent control make encourage tenants to
stay in units for too long or in units that no longer serve their needs, creating
a mismatch between apartments and occupants.
Empirical
studies of what happened in San Francisco, California and Cambridge, Massachusetts lend evidence to
these claims.
Overall, economists and critics
assert that while rent control might benefit current tenants or occupants,
longer term its impact is more destructive.
A parallel to this is what happened in 1978 with California’s
Proposition 13 that froze property taxes on existing housing. Its impact was to shift property taxes to new
construction, driving up its cost and leading to some of the rental shortage
and cost problems one sees lingering to this day.
Moreover, in the case of
Minneapolis, rent control cannot be examined in isolation, but in conjunction
with other policies, such as the 2040 Comprehensive Plan. It calls for significantly new construction
through the elimination of single gamily zoning. The hope is that increased
densification of housing will, among other things, reduce or stabilize
rents. Simply rezoning will not necessarily
produce the type of housing units that help middle class or low income households or ensure that historically segregated neighborhoods will equitably
integrate. Here, rent control may counteract
and benefits that come from Minneapolis
2040 by again decreasing incentives to build more units of any kind. It may push development into higher end
condos or shift development outside the city.
Finally, rent control may work well
when there is a surplus of units to prevent speculation. But as in the case of Minneapolis where there
is already a shortage of units, squeezing rents will not solve a pre-existing
problem, only make it worse.
How can one address the lack of
affordable housing? Specifically building
those types of units combined with rent stabilization policies is one way to do
it. Rental subsidies are another
solution. Three, Minneapolis is part of
a larger metro-wide housing market and it needs to operate in concert with
other jurisdictions or the Met Council to fix the problem. Four, consider alternative housing
strategies, such as encouraging the construction
of micro-housing. Five, more creative development solutions,
such as waivers on height or unit
numbers in return for dedicated construction of middle class or low
income units, should be considered. Six,
allow for pre-fab units, which are cheaper to build, to be sited in
Minneapolis.
Rent control alone is a crude
solution to a serious problem. The real
problem is that housing is a basic human
need commodified, meaning its delivery is mostly subject to the laws of marketplace. Rent control is a band aid on a larger
problem and if implemented wrongly it
produces secondary effects that distort housing markets for decades. Used more carefully and in conjunction with other strategies, it may serve as a partial
tool to addressing the problem that a free market delivery of housing produces.
Yes, I agree, Mr. David Schultz, this should be a comprehensive solution, all six points are important. Adequate housing construction of different cost will probably be decisive.
ReplyDelete